Nov 22 2013

The US attack on Germany’s Economic Policy: A Crisis of World Leadership

by Fabrizio Goria

Obama-MerkelIt is a war of words between the United States and Germany. Or maybe not. Certainly the latest US Treasury report on the international economic situation has stirred emotions, both because of the sharp language used in attacking Germany’s growth model, which is allegedly pushing the Eurozone into deflation, and because of the implicit confession that the US recovery is not as strong as previously thought. First it was the “datagate”, then the wiretapping on Angela Merkel, finally the spat on the economy: relations between Washington and Berlin have not been so tense for decades. The reasons however may be deeper than one might imagine.

The US are attacking Germany on the point of macroeconomic imbalances in the Eurozone. Under more normal circumstances, this would simply be a news story. In the post-Lehman Brothers world, however, it may represent something else. The US Treasury highlights how the prospected economic growth in the Eurozone will be entirely based on domestic demand and German exports. In order to sustain itself, Washington explains, Berlin is exploiting its competitive advantage to the detriment of Eurozone’s periphery. That is true, but is this not the same growth model that has been in use for the past 13 years? Why are these critical remarks made only now? Indeed, specific norms exist to avoid that a country may have a current account surplus larger than 6% of GDP on a three-year median value, but it is not Germany’s fault if the preconditions for such an unbalance have risen. Labour market reforms in Germany have been launched well before the European crisis broke out. Other member states, however, have not followed the same path and that, if one really wants to find a culprit of Germany’s performance, is the fault of Brussels, not of Berlin. Trying to keep under the same roof, namely the European common market, countries with evident imbalances in their current accounts deriving not only from different economic structures but from diverging ones has revealed itself a more complicated task than previously imagined. However, this is not a problem of the euro, or of Germany. It is a problem of the mentality and of the original euro project. Indeed, it has been known for long that Germany is the engine of Europe and why this is the case. Companies in the Eurozone depend on Berlin as much as Berlin depends on the Eurozone. One cannot break this circle. Not now, considering the precarious situation in which the European economy finds itself. Precisely for this reason the European approach to the crisis has been the opposite of the one in the US: fiscal consolidation first, growth afterwards. And in any case, the economy’s structures in the US and the EU are very different and using the same model would have been impossible.

The reason for the US Treasury burst has to be sought somewhere else. It would be a mistake to think that Washington is afraid of Berlin. Actually, Washington is afraid of itself. It is afraid of a domestic recovery which looks increasingly addicted to the FED’s quantitative easing measures, whose QE programme purchases US Treasury Bonds and Mortgage-Backed-Securities (MBS) for $85 billion per month. Washington fears that Europe may no longer be able to do what it has done in the last decades, namely to buy goods and services from the US. Indeed, after a drop in domestic demand in several economies, from Italy to France, from Spain to Ireland, now a drop in external demand is becoming apparent. This phenomenon has been noticed by Dirk Schumacher, a Goldman Sachs analyst, who has warned European policy-makers about what may happen once QE-generated liquidity will be withdrawn, the impact of which will be relevant for the Eurozone as well. And if demand in the Eurozone shrinks, either because of austerity policies or because of the QE withdrawal, negative consequences will certainly affect the US too.

Despite an improvement of the conjuncture, the US economy has several weaknesses. Only the exceptional regime of super-liquidity by the FED has helped avoid the worse. This result can be clearly read in the data provided by the FED itself, whose balance sheet has risen from $800 billion in 2007 to over $3,700 billion today. All these extraordinary measures had a double goal: to support domestic demand and to make financial markets thaw. This operation has been only half successful, given that, as recalled by the FED chairman Ban Bernanke, the real economy remains weak. And it is not that important that the S&P 500, Dow Jones and Nasdaq, Wall Street’s main indexes, are at their historical maximum. This is actually the product of the regime introduced by the FED by means of three consecutive rounds of QE easing. James Bullard, the FED St. Louis chief executive, has recently remarked that some economic sectors in the US may be experiencing a bubble as a result of the QE, and stated that “We are monitoring the prices of several assets, and although there is no evidence, there are risks”. Sectors under observation are two: real estate and high tech. But what is important is something else.

120px-Flags_USA_and_GermanyThe macroeconomic imbalances created by the US central bank after the Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy are much deeper than those created by Germany. The decision about the QE tapering, possibly postponed to the first quarter of 2014, will impact not only the Eurozone, but the entire global economy. The FED “dope” which has supported financial markets during the gloomiest period of the last twenty years may be remembered as one of the darkest pages of that institution’s history. According to the Global Financial Stability Report (GFSR) published by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), once QE will start to be withdrawn, potential losses on obligation portfolios may reach the $2,300 billion mark. This is because an end of QE would induce a 1% average rise of in government-issued bonds worldwide, which would cause losses up to 5.6% on global obligation portfolios. Far greater imbalances than those induced by Germany.

The US leadership is in clear decline. This phenomenon has been becoming obvious for a number of years, but in terms of the economic-financial profile the turning point has been perhaps the last G20 meeting in Saint Petersburg, during which the clash between the US and the BRICS was evident. Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa have openly attacked the US, guilty, according to their judgment, of having introduced too much liquidity in the financial markets. And that is true. The BRICS, in order to counter this monster that the US have been forced to create, have now established a fund in foreign reserves with a $100 billion in order to use it on the forex once the withdrawal of the QE will be started. Again, are these imbalances not much more relevant than those produced by Germany, together with the tacit approval of the EU Commission and the member states with the Eurozone? In order to understand this question it is probably necessary to ask another question first.

Are the US the same as in the past? Very simply, no. If it is true that the Eurozone is flirting with deflation, it is also true that the ECB is carefully watching out to avoid the recession becoming a stagnation which, in theory, may create even more damage. The US Treasury’s words therefore must be contextualised. Washington is becoming aware that its international power has been in decline for twenty years. […]

The “new world” will not be America-centred. The change in the global leadership, both economic and financial has already started, but nobody knows when it will be over. The Pew Research Center has highlighted this trend, underscoring how the majority of interviewees today (54%, they were 42% in 2008) think that in twenty years China will replace the US as world leader. According to George Magnus, one of the most brilliant economists of the UBS bank, this transition will be completed by 2050. According to Stephen King, chief economist at HSBC, by 2040. Instead of one single large macroeconomic area able to drag the global economy there will be smaller economic areas, more fragmented, which will contribute to change growth factors. Consequently, political relations among states will also change. From the intellectual monopoly of the US, whose growth model has been exported, with some modifications, to the emerging economies, there will be a shift to a new benchmark.

These are perhaps America’s last breaths as world leader. Its economic weakness has been impacting its international political position. And vice versa. But becoming aware of one’s own weakness is difficult, and even more leaving the stage to new leaders. As a result, the attack on German economic policies sounds more like a swan song rather than a warning to European policy makers.

The post was originally published in Italian by Linkiesta, English translation by Roberto Orsi .

_______________

Fabrizio Goria is business and finance correspondent of the Italian online news magazine Linkiesta.

Note: This article gives the views of the author, and not the position of the Euro Crisis in the Press blog, nor of the London School of Economics.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
This entry was posted in Germany, Uncategorized and tagged , , , , , . Bookmark the permalink.

9 Responses to The US attack on Germany’s Economic Policy: A Crisis of World Leadership

  1. Pingback: Effects on UK: The US attack on Germanys Economic Policy A Crisis of World | Euro Economy

  2. Pingback: Effects on Germany: The US attack on Germanys Economic Policy A Crisis of World | Euro Economy

  3. Pingback: Effects on Finland: The US attack on Germanys Economic Policy A Crisis of World | Euro Economy

  4. Pingback: Effects on Czech Rep.: The US attack on Germanys Economic Policy A Crisis of World | Euro Economy

  5. Pingback: Effects on Italy: The US attack on Germanys Economic Policy A Crisis of World | Euro Economy

  6. Filippo Da Fiume says:

    Simply thank You very much Mr. Tony Maher

  7. Tony Maher says:

    Apparently export dependency is completely detached from any negative economic outcomes especially when trade imbalances are discussed. In fact, according to the Berlin view, a trade surplus is always and everywhere a good thing – everyone should have one and no doubt when Mars opens for business everyone will have one.

    Meanwhile back on earth a substantial portion of Germany’s trade surplus was in fact extracted from the higher growth rates of relatively poor Southern European countries – a trade subsidy from the poor to the rich which defies the principles of comparative advantage that usually apply in trade between poorer and richer nations. Inevitably Germany has used much of the surplus capital generated by this surplus trade to fund further southern borrowing – not wisely but all too well. A net exporter of goods is (by definition) always a net exporter of capital. So this has been a vast vendor finance scheme in which German capital has been exported South to fund Germany’s trade surplus with the South.

    Of course Germany has been unable to pull off this trick with either Poland or Czech because these countries have kept their own currency and therefore maintained their modest but growing trade surplus with Germany. There is therefore a very big difference between Germany acting as an engine for her poorer trade partners growth and Germany acting as a black hole which consumes her poorer partners growth.

    The Euro has a lot to answer for.

    Instead we are presented with a version of history in which the euro era was Europe’s last golden opportunity to become…..what else but Germany? Everybody exporting more than they import. But if they had all been surplus exporters who would then have absorbed Germany’s surplus? How could Germany’s own economy have grown in a Europe full of Germany’s?

    And how good has this exporting outperformance really been for Germany? The US’s trend growth has certainly outstripped Germany’s since the 80’s. A US trend growth rate north of 2.5% compares very favourably with Germany’s paltry 0.9%. Even the last two years of high growth were preceded by a period in which German GDP fell further (and faster) than any other developed economy. Her long term trend hasn’t budged and this year she is forecasting just 0.8% growth! Meanwhile German household wealth is astonishingly low, taxes on average incomes is eyewateringly high (marginal tax rates are punitive for the largest cohort of taxpayers). German household consumption is low. The German service sector is an embarrassment. How is this a desireable model for a developed economy?

    The fact is that exporting is a poor man’s game. When she is number 1 exporter China can boast a growth rate of 12% whereas when Germany is top exporter all she has to show for it is 0.9%.

    Both Japan and Germany cannot wean themselves off the trade appetites they formed in their first desperate years of post war rebuilding. They are still starving the living standards of their own workers in order to allow their exporters to binge feed of other people’s tables. In good times this is considered very bad manners. In bad times it is a legitimate justification for the erection of trade barriers.

    Over time trade must balance – even German trade. The global economy is a closed system and we cannot in fact export to Mars. When the US treasury is stating that a rich region (our new Germanised Europe) that contributes only net supply to the global economy leaving everyone else to supply the net demand is a region whose trade access to US (& global) markets will need to be restricted in future. Beggar thy neighbour will not work with the Americans – or anyone else.

    • Roberto Orsi says:

      The Germans are already among the largest importers of the planet. The pro capita import is $14,902, against $5,747 for the US. In Germany you can buy anything from any part of the world, and the Germans are clearly not depriving themselves of any imported good, from cars to food, from electronic goods to energy. I guess that the rest of the world does not offer to the German consumer anything which he is going to buy in even greater quantities. I cannot imagine what the Germans can buy from the rest of the world for hundreds of billion euros, considering that their demand of imported goods is already saturated. The point is instead that the rest of the world has an insatiable demand for German goods, possibly because of their higher quality. The resulting surplus, I am afraid, cannot be reduced simply by boosting German wages, because this is unlikely to be translated into massively higher levels of import, certainly not for the figures we are looking at.
      And by the way, living standards in German cities, as confirmed by numerous studies, are considerably higher than in US cities.

      • Tony Maher says:

        Being amongst the top importers in the world is merely the effect derived from the primary cause – Germany is the biggest exporter in the world. Therefore Germany does not provide net demand to the eurozone, the EU or the wider world. This simply means that Germany requires the growth of other economies to provide her with a living. They must fund a negative current account if Germany is to go on enjoying the benefits of a positive current account.

        “Your markets belong to us but your debts belong to you” is Germany’s European ideal – both as pronounced and as implemented.

        You go on to say that it is, to all intents and purposes, impossible for the Germans to import more than they do. Let us accept that highly counter intuitive argument for the purpose of this discussion .

        If, as you say, German policy cannot be effective in reducing these enormous trade imbalances (and the resulting economic divergence the imbalances cause) then it rests with Germany’s partners to restrict her access to their markets.

        Germany’s trade surplus can be instantly eradicated by Germany’s customers. Whilst that will be a violation of the treaties it is still the inevitable end point for countries already experiencing great depression levels of unemployment and crashing living standards.

        You can either liquidate your own economy or you can liquidate Germany’s trade surplus – there is only one outcome to that policy choice.

        The price of Germany’s continued structural mercantalism will be the destruction of the single market……..

Comments are closed.